When the New York Stock Exchange was founded in March 1817, they ba...
A regressive tax is one where the tax rate decreases as the amount ...
This is no longer true. Thanks to rising metal prices, since 2006 t...
Another thing to note is that since the publication of this paper, ...
According to a more recent 2015 FDIC National Survey of Unbanked an...
The U.S. convenience store industry, with more than 154,000 stores...
how do i download a paper to print or read on another device?
ELIMINATING THE PENNY FROM THE U. S.
COINAGE SYSTEM:
AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
Raymond E. Lombra
Pennsylvania State University
INTRODUCTION
With the introduction of the new dollar coin in early 2000, and reported "short-
ages" of pennies during 1999 and 2000, questions have again been raised about the
desirability of considering a further restructuring of the coinage system in the United
States. More specifically, some members of Congress and others have called for elimi-
nation of the penny. It is ironic, indeed, that arguments calling for eliminating the
penny and rounding prices are occurring as we are in the process of moving away
from the rounding implicit in quoting stocks in fractions (eighths and sixteenths for
example) and toward decimal trading in the expectation that this will yield substan-
tial savings for investors.
The purpose of this paper is to examine the major economic consequences of re-
moving the penny from circulation. The major findings are easily summarized:
• Removing the penny from circulation will have significant adverse direct effects
on consumers. The resulting need to round prices will generate a rounding tax of
no less than $600 million a year. Moreover, the "rounding tax" is likely to be
regressive, affecting the poor and other disadvantaged groups disproportionately.
• The inflationary impact of rounding will probably be small. However, even a small
effect will cumulate over time to a considerable sum. Utilizing the results of simu-
lations of the degree of rounding likely to occur, and Congressional Budget Office
estimates of the effects of higher prices on Federal government outlays, show
that removing the penny would raise government outlays by about $950 million
in 2005 and by $2 billion in 2010.
• Rounding could also have significant negative effects on firms, given the narrow
profit margins in convenience stores and supermarkets, the possible adverse ef-
fects on theft deterrence, the costs of training cashiers and associated productiv-
ity losses, and the high costs associated with non-cash mediated transactions.
Such considerations point toward changes in the structure of prices designed to
take advantage of rounding and thereby raise prices overall.
Raymond E. Lombra: 116 Sparks Building, Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA
16802. E-mail: RL3@PSU.edu
Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 27, No. 4, Fall 2001
433
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
434 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
• The government's net earnings on penny production and distribution (about $25
million in 1999) - seigniorage - and the Mint's focus on continuing productivity
gains and cost control suggest that the penny will remain a profit center for the
government for some time to come.
THE NET EFFECT OF ROUNDING PRICES TO THE NEAREST 5-CENT
INCREMENT
It has long been recognized that removing the penny from circulation would re-
quire that cash purchases be rounded to the nearest nickel. The most commonly men-
tioned scheme (which appeared in H.R. 3761, "The Price Rounding Act of 1989") speci-
fied that if the total, including tax, of a cash purchase ended in a 3,4,8, or 9, the
resulting sum would be rounded up to the nearest nickel, while if the total ended in
1,2,6, or 7 the resulting sum would be rounded down to the nearest nickel. For ex-
ample, a total bill at the cash register of $2.34 would be rounded up to $2.35, while a
total of $2.36 would be rounded down to $2.35. Payments by check, credit or debit
card would not require any rounding.
Many advocates of removing the penny assume that the net effects of such a
rounding scheme will be close to zero - on average, the number of transactions lead-
ing to rounding up will be roughly offset by the number leading to rounding down.
Even the aforementioned GAO study offered no evidence on the issue, suggesting, at
least implicitly, that such an assumption was not unreasonable; " In theory, rounding
could be designed to be fair so that one-half of the transactions would be rounded up
and one-half rounded down" [1996, 11] . A moment's thought suggests such a "theory"
is predicated on the distribution of the final digits of prices of individual goods, and,
more to the point, the distribution of the final digits of sales at the cash register, being
relatively flat, with the proportion of prices/sales ending in each digit from "0" to "9"
being roughly 10 percent.
To move away from the world of assumption and speculation, I present a set of
data and methods for getting at the direct, indirect, distributional, and dynamic (over
time) effects of such a change in our payments system.
Direct Effects
I begin with a careful experiment designed to simulate the net effects of rounding
on consumers. I was able to obtain, on a confidential basis, the "price book" for a
typical convenience store in a large chain of such stores in the mid-Atlantic region.
Focusing on just such a class of stores makes sense since most of their transactions
(ignoring gasoline) are in cash. Table 1 shows the distribution of the final digits for
the prices of the 3,585 separate items sold in the typical store. (Data were gathered in
January 2000.) As is obvious and has been documented for a long time [Twedt, 1965],
the overwhelming proportion of prices end in 9.
The next step is to simulate 5,000 transactions of from one to three items each
across the full spectrum of 3,585 items. (I also conducted simulations with 1,000 and
10,000 transactions; the results are virtually identical to those reported below.) Each
transaction represents, in effect, a single customer, purchasing a random set of one to
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ELIMINATING THE PENNY 435
TABLE 1
Distribution of Prices in a Representative Convenience Store
Last Digit of Price Number of Items Percent of Total
0 8 0.2 %
1 2 0.1
2 6 0.2
3 19 0.5
4 323 9.0
5 134 3.7
6 103 2.9
7 4 0.1
8 27 0.8
9 2,959 82.5
Total 3,585 100.0
three items from among all those available in the store. The bill is calculated for each
transaction and the rounding scheme described above is applied to the total. The
results show that between 60 percent and 93 percent of the transactions result in round-
ing up f with the lower figuring resulting when up to three items are purchased and
the higher figure resulting when one or two items are purchased. These results are
not surprising given the distribution of prices in Table 1. With available research
showing the average value of a cash transaction in year 2000 dollars to be in the $5-6
range [Humphrey, 1994, 61], and the data available from the chain of convenience
stores supplying the price data, I am confident that focusing on 1-3 transactions per
customer captures the representative range of cash transactions in such venues. 1
The last step in the simulation is to arrive at the total number of cash transac-
tions in the economy in a given year and apply the above percentages to estimate the
range of net rounding in dollar terms. As a wise sage once said, easier said than done.
Hancock and Humphrey put it this way, "data on cash transactions represent esti-
mates from one-shot surveys or expert guesses and are woefully inadequate com-
pared to data for noncash transactions" [1998, 1576].
Proceeding with the appropriate degree of caution and appreciation for the lack
of precision inherent in any calculation, I utilize data provided by the American Bankers
Association which itself is drawn from the widely used "Nilson Report" produced by
HSN Consultants of Oxnard, CA. For the year 2000, the number of transactions by
consumers is estimated at 106 billion. Hancock and Humphrey report that estimates
of the proportion of total transactions, which are in cash, range from 50 percent to 83
percent [1998, 1576]. Table 2 applies this range for cash transactions to the range for
the proportion of cash transactions rounded up from the simulations above to arrive
at an estimated upper and lower bound for the dollar value of rounding for the economy
as a whole.
As is shown, the estimated range for the direct effect is $318 million to $818
million, with a midpoint of $598 million. (The use of a range is appropriate given the
underlying imprecision mentioned above.) I consider the estimates in the table con-
servative since transactions totals ending in "3" or "8" are rounded up by two cents
rather than the one cent assumed for all transactions in the underlying calculations
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
436 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
TABLE 2
Net Rounding: Direct Effects
Proportion of Cash Cash Transactions as Proportion of Total Transactions
Transactions Rounded Up 50 percent 83 percent
60 percent 53 billion transactions X .6 = 88 billion transactions X .6 =
31.8 billion X $.01 = $318 million 52.8 billion X $.01 = $528 million
93 percent 53 billion transactions X.93 = 88 billion transactions X.93 =
49.3 billion X $.01 = $493 million 81.8 billion X $0.1 = $818 million
Based on estimate of 106 billion consumer transactions in 2000 [Nilson Report]; assumes rounding of only
one cent per occurrence.
and I have not assumed any change in pricing behavior by retail outlets to take ad-
vantage of the rounding scheme.
To provide some intuition and context for the estimates, if each of the 200 million
U.S. residents aged 16 and over experienced a penny of net rounding up per day, this
would amount to $700 million dollars per year (200 million persons X $.01 X 350 days
per year).
These calculations illustrate a basic premise - even a seemingly trivial effect per
individual per day adds up to a nontrivial "tax" on consumers in the aggregate. 2
Indirect Effects
By definition, the rounding tax estimated above would raise the overall price
level, as measured, say, by the Consumer Price Index. The effect would be quantita-
tively small. With consumer spending in current dollars at $6.5 trillion in 1999, the
$598 million midpoint of the rounding tax range would represent an increase in prices
of about 1/100 of one percent ($598 million/ $6.5 trillion = 0.000092).3
While the effect on the CPI would hardly be noticeable, in dollar terms, even such
a seemingly small effect could cumulate over time to a considerable sum given that
virtually all government outlays (for example, social security benefits, welfare pay-
ments, interest on the public debt, and items procured) and many private sector costs,
such as wages and salaries, are indexed or tied, formally or informally to the CPI.
To illustrate, the Congressional Budget Office [2000, Appendix C] estimates that
an increase of one percentage point in the annual rate of inflation beginning in Janu-
ary 2000 would raise total outlays by $103 billion by 2005 and $219 billion by 2010.
Thus, if the rounding tax pushes up prices by 0.92/100 of one percent, Federal govern-
ment outlays would be about $948 million higher in 2005 ($103 billion X 0.0092 =
$948 million) and by $2 billion in 2010 ($219 billion X 0.0092 = $2.01 billion).
Taken together, the direct and indirect effects on the government and private
sectors would be no less than $1.5 billion over five years and $2.5 billion over a de-
cade. I say "no less than" because I view the estimates as conservative and static,
making no allowance, for example, for strategic adjustments in firms' pricing prac-
tices.
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ELIMINATING THE PENNY 437
Distributional Effects
In a caring and pluralistic society, estimates of aggregate, economy-wide effects
need to be accompanied with an analysis of the incidence of the potential "tax" on
consumers. More specifically, we need to examine whether the aggregate effects will
fall disproportionately on any particular segment of society. Unfortunately, available
data suggest that those least able to shoulder such costs will bear a disproportionate
share of the overall burden.
Recent Federal Reserve surveys [Kennickell, et al., 2000, 9; Hogarth and O'Donnell,
1999] indicate that 9.5 percent of American families do not have checking (transac-
tions) accounts - a total of nearly 10 million households. The vast majority of these
families (82.6 percent) had incomes of less than $25,000 and were nonwhite or His-
panic (57.1 percent).
Since only cash transactions will be subject to rounding, it follows that removing
the penny from circulation will impose a regressive tax on those making a dispropor-
tionate share of their transactions in cash- the poor and under-represented minority
members of our society. Regrettably, this implies that the existing regressivity of the
sales tax will be reinforced by the rounding tax.
Dynamic (Over Time) Effects
The direct and indirect effects enumerated above are essentially static in nature,
implying that all other factors driving pricing decisions are held constant. In moving
to an assessment of the dynamic reactions of firms which will govern the financial
effects of removing the penny over time, some have suggested that firms might round
down to attract customers or, at a minimum, that firms would not arrange their prices
in a way to take advantage of the rounding scheme. Such contentions fly in the face of
basic microeconomic principles which are based on the fundamental premise that the
behavior of firms, that is, their employment, production, advertising, and pricing de-
cisions, are guided by a straightforward objective - the desire to maximize profits.
In a recent study for the National Bureau of Economic Research, Besley and Rosen
examined the effects of sales taxes on firms' pricing decisions. Their findings:
For some commodities, we cannot reject that taxes are shifted on a
one-for-one basis. For others, commodity taxes are over shifted - a
ten-cent increase in the revenue extracted from the sale of these com-
modities leads to an increase in their prices of more than a dime. The
finding that some commodities exhibit over shifting ... is consistent
with the predictions of certain theoretical models of imperfect compe-
tition that seem like reasonable characterizations of the retail sector.
[1998, 26-27]4
These findings suggest such taxes are even more regressive and burdensome than
conventionally thought. Moreover, as the discussion below makes clear, they apply
directly to the "rounding tax" under examination here.
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
438 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
In discussing the possible removal of the penny at the 2 December 1998 commit-
tee meeting, members of the National Association of Convenience Stores were told
that the net profit on an average transaction in a convenience store is only 3 percent
or 6 to 7 cents. Comparing the two-cent difference in rounding up a penny versus
rounding down a penny, it was stated that such a difference "accounts for over 30
percent of that net profit and, therefore, all prices in the convenience store would
have to be raised" [National Association of Convenience Stores, 1998] .
This observation - a simple, straightforward statement about shifting - is criti-
cal, because it has been contended by proponents of removing the penny that price
structures would not respond in an unfavorable (to the consumer) fashion to a round-
ing scheme. What evidence there is suggests we will get a rounding tax and pricing
adjustments by firms to both shift and take advantage of the tax.5
Some have contended that removing the penny from circulation would save worker
productivity lost in conjunction with handling pennies when making change, thereby
permitting rounding down. Such claims of improved efficiency are vacuous in the
absence of evidence bearing on the issue. At the same meeting of the NACS, it was
reported that "the offset in cost of handling the penny does not even compare to the 30
percent..." [ibid.] of the net profit which could be lost from rounding down.
Reinforcing the possible negative effects of rounding on profit margins, in the
absence of adjusting the price structure, are the net costs associated with any induced
shifts of payments from cash to non-cash media. Table 3 [Hancock and Humphrey,
1998, 1613] provides evidence on the average cost of accepting different payment
instruments at supermarkets in the United States.
As they note, "the costs include the time it takes to complete a transaction, the
wage and fringe benefits of the various accepting/verifying/accounting employees,
armored courier costs (for cash), check and other fraud expenses, bank charges, elec-
tronic network transaction fees, and credit card fees" [1998, 1612, n.68]. Whether
based on sales value or per transaction, cash is always cheapest, and by a wide mar-
gin!
Theft Deterrence
Lest one underestimate the set of issues surrounding what happens at the cash
register, it is important to note that the high incidence of prices ending with a "9" in
Table 1 is no accident:
Department stores first started the (odd) pricing method to eliminate
shrinkage at the cash register caused by the pocket-bookkeeping
method among sales personnel. Even-priced merchandise often would
be paid for in exact amount direct from the shoppers' purse. The clerk
would then serve another customer or two before ringing up a sale.
When prices were changed to odd amounts, making change from pocket
became obvious and correct change usually required a trip back to the
register. [Department of the Treasury, 1979, 2; see also Twedt, 1965]
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ELIMINATING THE PENNY 439
TABLE 3
Costs of Receiving Different Payment Instruments for U.S. Supermarkets
By Transaction Volume By $100 of Sales Value
Cash $0.07 57 $0.52 35
Debit carda $0.30 2 $0.94 3
Checkb $0.43 33 $1.20 49
Credit Card $0.81 3 $2.27 5
Other0 - 5 - 7
Food Marketing Institute [1994]. a. Refers to an on-line debit, with settlement through the ACH. b. A
verified check reduces fraud losses and its cost per transaction (per $100 of sales) is somewhat lower at
$0.37 ($1.05). c. Primarily food stamps, a government-sponsored food welfare program.
The National Association of Convenience Stores website (http://www.
cstorecentral.com) is filled with stories on the rising volume of employee theft and its
link to what happens (or doesn't happen) at the register. One would expect strong
underlying support for anything that helps control employee theft and forces cash
transactions through a register. The accounting, tax, and profit implications are sig-
nificant for both the public and private sectors. Eliminating the penny from circula-
tion obviously moves in the opposite direction.
Cashless Society?
Lastly, some have contended that ongoing technological advances will mean that
electronic payments will increasingly displace cash transactions, perhaps eliminat-
ing them all together in the foreseeable future. This contention ignores the increas-
ingly wide availability of ATMs [Weiner, 1999] , which makes it more convenient from
a consumer's perspective to acquire and utilize cash than otherwise. Furthermore,
the costs of cash vs. alternative payments media, shown in Table 3, suggest that
profit-seeking firms would be rather hesitant to behave in a way that resulted in a
significant decline in the number of cash transactions unless and until the relative
costs of cash vs. other payments media are much more favorable.
REMOVING LOW DENOMINATION COINS FROM CIRCULATION: AN
HISTORICAL AND COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE
It is an undeniable fact that the real value of the Lincoln penny today is about 1/
20 of its value when introduced in 1909 and that inflation reduces the use and useful-
ness of low-denomination coins [Goldin, 1985]. Interesting though these facts are,
they do not, by themselves, tell us anything about the effects of removal. In an ideal
world, historical evidence and the experiences of other countries might help to pin
down the major economic effects of removing the penny from circulation. Proponents
of removal often cite the fact that over the last twenty years several countries (France,
Spain, the Netherlands, Australia, New Zealand, and the United Kingdom) have re-
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
440 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
moved their lowest denomination coins from circulation (the equivalent of a V2 cent
coin or the penny) with no discernable economic effects. I have conducted an exten-
sive search of the relevant archives in these countries and cannot find a study of the
subsequent economic effects. Proponents, I presume, would equate the absence of a
careful study of the effects within these much smaller economies (Australia's GDP,
for example, is eight percent of GDP in the United States) with the proposition that
the effects were in fact negligible, and hence would be in the United States. Such an
approach strikes me as a weak platform on which to base a significant change in our
coinage system; the absence of evidence does not equal zero impact. A good example
is provided by the fact that the Army stopped using pennies in European commissar-
ies and exchanges (non-profit-seeking entities) in 1980; those proposing removal of
the penny cite the alleged lack of problems as evidence that the effects would be
negligible for the economy as a whole. In its deeper excavation of the contention, the
GAO reported to the Congress that: "the facilities often rounded down to minimize
complaints" [1996, 10].
Seigniorage
What discussion one does find in the popular press within the various countries is
that "negative seigniorage" - that is, the cost of producing the low denomination coins
exceeding their face value - did often operate as an important driving force, that is,
as a necessary condition behind the subsequent elimination. In considering the U.S.
case, the Mint reports that the full costs of production and distribution for the penny
have been approximately eight-tenths of a cent in recent years. With penny produc-
tion of nearly 12 billion in 1999, this implies positive seigniorage - that is, a net profit
of about $24 million (12 billion pennies X 0.2/100 = $24 million). Given the Strategic
Plan for the Mint (www.usmint.gov), which emphasizes continuing productivity gains
and cost control, it would appear that penny production will remain a profit center for
the Government for some time to come.6
A Case Study: The Euro Coinage System
In the context of the recent establishment of the European Monetary Union, par-
ticipating governments and finance ministries had to confront the question of the
structure of the accompanying coinage system. After careful reflection and consider-
ation, it was decided to include a penny equivalent. The German Finance Ministry
provided the following background and rationale:
If a euro one-cent coin were not introduced, public opinion might re-
gard this as a sign of weakness in the euro and confidence in the
stability of the common European currency might suffer as a result....
... the purpose is to supply coins needed for monetary transaction. For
this, minting the low-denomination euro coins is indispensable. Abol-
ishing the low-denomination coins is out of the question for reasons of
price policy as well. If such coins were no longer available, we would
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ELIMINATING THE PENNY 441
have to pass regulations concerning pricing or rounding ... It would be
hard to reconcile such government intervention in pricing with our
economic principles. [Letter, 18 December 1998]
CONCLUSIONS
The 1996 GAO study of the economic effects of removing the penny from circula-
tion concludes: "In analyzing these factors, we found no clear path that would lead
either to a substantial benefit to the Federal government or a clearly expressed pre-
ferred course of action by the American public" [1996, 11]. In this more comprehen-
sive study, I also could not identify any net benefits associated with price rounding
and the removal of the penny. Admittedly, the calculations of the degree of rounding
and the quantitative effects on the economy and Americans, although done carefully
and conservatively, are subject to some unknown degree of error. To my way of think-
ing, such uncertainty reinforces the analytical arguments presented. Unless it can be
demonstrated that the adverse effects will be negligible, then the benefits of remov-
ing the penny must be sufficiently large to outweigh a reasonable estimate of the
adverse effects. I find the potential adverse effects considerable.
As the government's experience with the metric system, the bicentennial $2 bill,
and various attempts to overhaul health care so poignantly demonstrate, the public
must be convinced of a pressing need for and clear net benefits associated with chang-
ing anything that has become embroidered into the social and economic fabric of soci-
ety. The evidentiary requirement for removing the penny from circulation does not
yet appear to meet this standard. Of course, if and when seigniorage turns negative,
inflation reduces the real value of a penny substantially further, and, more generally,
the benefits of elimination (what might be called "convenience") rise relative to the
costs, then removal will be more attractive. In the meantime, with the "decimaliza-
tion" of equity prices leading to a substantial narrowing of spreads and accompanying
reductions in trading costs to investors, it is clear that a penny here and a penny
there, be it at the convenience store, supermarket or stock market, add up to a sub-
stantial sum that can either help consumers (decimalization) or tax them (eliminat-
ing the penny).
NOTES
The author wishes to thank the editors and referees of this Journal for helpful suggestions.
1. I also conducted simulations that allowed for sales taxes on a random proportion of the items com-
posing each transaction. The results reported above were not materially affected. This is reasonable:
first, the sales tax is itself routinely rounded up; second, in most jurisdictions food is exempt from
sales taxes [Federation of Tax Administrators, February 2000]; hence, the majority of the items in a
convenience store would not be taxable. As one referee has noted, however, if the distribution of
prices shown in Table 1 was flatter, or the "average" consumer purchased 4-5 goods per cash transac-
tion, the proportion of cash transactions rounded up would decline.
2. The same point has been vividly illustrated by the recent move on the New York and other stock
exchanges involving pricing stocks in cents instead of fractions of a dollar. Pricing in fractions is, in
effect, a kind of rounding scheme. The early evidence [Henry, 2000; Chakravarty and Wood, 2000a,
2000b] suggests the change is resulting in a substantial drop in trading costs for investors.
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
442 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
3. For a compelling theoretical analysis, see Chen where he concluded, "A shortage or an absence of a
desirable denomination would be inflationary" [1976, 183]. As he argues, the decline in money de-
mand would result in a rise in velocity and prices.
4. See papers reviewed in Anderson [1990], which examine the relationship between grocery store
prices or grocery store profits and market concentration. They find a positive relationship and con-
clude many local markets are imperfectly competitive.
5. And make no mistake, retail price books are geared to change prices rapidly and to set the final digits
of prices with considerable precision; see, for example, Sisel and Lambert [1997] and Roberts and
Sanquist [1997].
6. One referee correctly emphasized the important role of seigniorage and suggested that Sumner's
analysis [1993] of privatizing the mint may yield some insights regarding a more optimal set of
production and transactions arrangements.
REFERENCES
Anderson, K. A Review of Structure-Performance Studies in Grocery Retailing. Washington, D.C.: Bu-
reau of Economics, Federal Trade Commission, 1990.
Besley, T. and Rosen, H. Sales Taxes and Prices: An Empirical Analysis. Boston: National Bureau of
Economic Research, Working Paper # 6667, July 1998.
Chakravarty, S. and Wood, R. The Effect of Decimal Trading on Market Liquidity. University of Mem-
phis Working Paper, September 2000a.
University of Memphis Working Paper, October 2000b.
Chen, C. Currency Denominations and the Price Level. Journal of Political Economy, 1976, 179-83.
Congressional Budget Office. The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2001-2010. Washing-
ton, D.C., January 2000.
Department of the Treasury. An Assessment of United States Currency and Coin Systems with Long
Range Planning Recommendations. Washington, D.C., 1979.
General Accounting Office. Future of the Penny: Options for Congressional Consideration. Washington,
D.C.,16 July 1996.
26 June 1997.
Goldin, E. Statistical Analysis of Coins Lost. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, January 1985,
36-42.
Hancock, D. and Humphrey, D. Payment Transactions, Instruments, and Services: A Survey. Journal
of Banking and Finance, 1998, 1573-624.
Henry, D. Investors find cents make sense as trading costs drop. USA Today, 8 September 2000, lb.
Hogarth, J. and O'Donnell, K. Banking Relationships of Lower-Income Families and the Governmen-
tal Trend Toward Electronic Payment. Federal Reserve Bulletin, July 1999, 459-73.
Humphrey, D. Delivering Deposit Services: ATM Versus Branches. Economic Quarterly, Federal Re-
serve Bank of Richmond, 1994, 59-81.
Kennickell, A., Starr-McCluer, M., and Surette, B. Recent Changes in U.S. Family Finances: Results
from the 1998 Survey of Consumer Finances. Federal Reserve Bulletin, January 2000, 1-29.
Ministry of Finance. Federal Republic of Germany. Letter, 18 December 1998.
National Association of Convenience Stores. Minutes: Auto Safe Subcommittee of the Device Inte-
gration Committee. Phoenix, AZ, 2 December 1998.
Roberts, A. and Sanquist, B. The Good, the Bad and the Ugly of POS Scanning, National Association of
Convenience Stores. Dallas. TX. 1997.
Sisel, R. and Lambert, S. The Nuts and Bolts of Price Book Management. National Association of
Convenience Stores, Dallas, TX, 1997.
Sumner, S. Privatizing the Mint. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1993, 13-29.
Twedt, D. Does the "9 Fixation" in Retail Pricing Really Promote Sales? Journal of Marketing, October
1965, 54-5.
Weiner, S. Electronic Payments in the U.S. Economy: An Overview. Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City, Fourth Quarter 1999, 53-64.
This content downloaded from 132.77.150.148 on Thu, 02 Jun 2016 03:09:04 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

Discussion

Another thing to note is that since the publication of this paper, the use of credit and debit cards as well as online payments have dramatically risen, but these modes of payment and financial services are less available to poor and unbanked individuals, making this regressive tax even more regressive if items purchased by check,credit or debit card wouldn't require rounding. how do i download a paper to print or read on another device? This is no longer true. Thanks to rising metal prices, since 2006 the US mint has had to spend more money to produce and distribute both nickels and pennies than the coins are actually worth. In 2016, according to a report from the U.S. Government Accountability Office, it costs 1.7 cents to make a penny and 8 cents to make a nickel. Therefore, the US government is not making profits from making and distributing pennies and this argument cannot be used. A regressive tax is one where the tax rate decreases as the amount subject to taxation increases. Regressive describes a distribution effect on income or expenditure and in terms of individual income and wealth, a regressive tax imposes a greater burden (relative to resources) on the poor than on the rich: there is an inverse relationship between the tax rate and the taxpayer's ability to pay, as measured by assets, consumption, or income. In this case, removing the penny, the smallest denomination of currency, would affect poorer people disproportionally more, so it is regressive. The U.S. convenience store industry, with more than 154,000 stores nationwide selling fuel, food and merchandise, serves 160 million customers daily— half of the U.S. population—and has sales that are 10.8% of total U.S. retail and food service sales. NACS has 2,100 retailer and 1,750 supplier members from more than 50 countries and was founded on August 14, 1961. When the New York Stock Exchange was founded in March 1817, they based their pricing system on the Spanish trading system. Over 400 years ago, Spanish traders would use a currency of Spanish gold doubloons for trade that they would divide into two, four and eight pieces that they would count on their fingers. They would not use their thumbs for counting, so Spanish gold doubloons had a base of eight with the smallest denomination 1/8. Instead of a base of eight, the New York Stock exchanged started with a base of sixteen and the smallest denomination was 1/16th. On April 9th, 2001, the SEC ordered all US stock markets to switch to a decimal system. An interesting development in the way prices are quoted is the SEC's tick pilot program, which increases the tick size (smallest price variation allowed) from 1 cent to 5 cents, with some restrictions across different securities. The goal of the program is to determine if liquidity in low volume equities can be improved by increasing the incentive for market makers to provide quotes. The logic here is that when the smallest possible spread is five cents, not one cent, market makers are happier because they can buy at the lower price and sell at the higher one, and make a five cent profit (assuming the price doesn't change). The program finished putting all 800 or so securities into the program as of late October and we're still waiting on preliminary research into results. Edit: If you're interested in learning more about tick size, Larry Harris had an excellent paper in 1994 about minimum price variation. According to a more recent 2015 FDIC National Survey of Unbanked and Underbanked households, 7.0 percent of households in the United States were unbanked in 2015. This proportion represents approximately 9.0 million households. An additional 19.9 percent of U.S. households (24.5 million) were underbanked, meaning that the household had a checking or savings account but also obtained financial products and services outside of the banking system.